On Derivatives
This approach to describing the global system of derivatives returns to Karl Marx’s assertion that there is an essential “divergence between price and value.” [46] There can be no fundamental price because what is fundamental to a commodity is its value, which perpetually changes besides, since value is historically and socially determined. Derivatives “are predicated on the notion that there are no ‘fundamentals’—all asset values have particular temporal and spatial determination, and prices are forever changing, and in unsystematic ways.” [47] Derivatives package conversions of different forms of capital, thereby making commensurable all sorts of “bits” of capital. They “are money (they perform a money function in pricing) and commodities (they are traded products) at the same time.” [48] Let us compare this characterization to Marx’s tripartite definition of money: (i) means of payment/exchange, (ii) measure of value, i.e. price, and (iii) money as money, a unique kind of commodity, which can be hoarded by the miser and transformed into a phase of capital by the capitalist. The one feature lost in the derivative form(s) of money is the possibility to hoard it. If banking capital, credit, interest-bearing capital, and so on, represent the formal subsumption of money by capital, then the derivative represents its real subsumption. Derivatives, as a global form of commodity money, “readily convert one form of money into another and a wide range of commodities into an even wider range of monetary units.” [49] Capital, by and for itself, moved the market “towards a new foundation to global money: financial derivatives.” [50] They provide, on an ongoing and flexible basis, “a network of anchors” for international exchange. Market stability exists today solely inasmuch as it is assumed by individual market participants: they “operative ‘as if’ the global financial system were stable.” [51]